Editing
Fixed-period BOND
Jump to navigation
Jump to search
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
A fixed-period BOND is a [[BOND tokens|BOND token]] which expires after a fixed lifetime <math>L_B</math>. This page details the design of the contracts which govern these tokens so their valuation is fair. The variables of payout rate, the expiration time<ref>Expiration date, lifetime, term, and period are all interchangeable terminology for the amount of time a BOND is active, denoted <math>L_B</math>.</ref>, and the value of the BOND are dependent on each other. A DAO can choose two of the variables at will, then solve for the third to determine a fair contract using REP tokenomics theory. The results and notation from the [[Reputation tokenomics|reputation tokenomics page]] are used here derive the formulas governing fixed-period BOND contracts under the assumptions that a DAO's underlying REP tokens have infinite lifetime and when they have finite lifetime, under the further assumptions that the fees the DAO earns are constant. Variable-period BONDs can be programmed with more complicated formulas as discussed [[Riskless BONDs|here]]. == Overview == Suppose we wish to pay a developer a bounty worth <math>$b</math>, but we do so BONDs which have a fixed expiration date of <math>L_B</math>. These fixed-period BONDs pay out the same as a REP token would by participating in the REP salary. Our goal is to find formulas determining how large we should set the expiration date given the rate of payout and the value. When we pay the developer with <math>q</math> newly minted BOND tokens, which dilutes the total REP in the DAO as fees are now shared with the <math>q+R</math> tokens. The number <math>q</math> of tokens determines the rate of payout, as a larger <math>q</math> means a larger share of the REP salary. The exact rate of payout for <math>q</math> BOND token is proportional to the incoming fees as <math>f'q/(q+R)</math>. Depending on whether the REP token design of the DAO has REP tokens with finite or infinite lifetime we get different formulas for how long the lifetime <math>L_B</math> should be set for a fixed-period BOND. == Mechanism design == === Fixed-period BOND contracts under infinite-lifetime REP === Under the assumption that a DAO's REP lifetime is unbounded, <math>L= \infty</math>, we wish to find the lifetime <math>L_B</math> we should set for a BOND so that it will have a particular value. In this case the income stream <math>f_B^1(t)</math> of one BOND token is the same as one REP token <math>f_0^1(t)</math> <math display="block">f_B^1(t)=\int_{0}^{t} \frac{f'(s)}{q(s)+R(s)}ds</math> until the BOND expires. In general, we have <math display="inline">R(t)=R_0+ \int_{0}^{t} m*f'(s)ds.</math> The term <math>q(s)</math> represents all the BONDs which are active at time <math>t=s</math>. Now suppose you want to find the lifetime <math>L_B</math> of a BOND that will give an expected payout of <math>$b</math> for <math>q</math> tokens. We therefore hope to solve the equation<math display="block">qf_B^1(L_B)=b</math> However, the terms <math>L_B</math> and <math>f'</math> are complicated. <math>L_B</math> is a stopping time, and <math>f'</math> is a stochastic process. Nevertheless, these terms behave relatively well, since we know the expected value <math>E[f_B^1(t)]</math> will be an increasing function of <math>t</math>, because <math>f_B^1(t)</math> is increasing, because <math>f'(s)\geq0</math>. Simply taking the expected value <math display="block">E_0 \left[f_B^1(t) \right ]=\int_{0}^{t}E_0 \left [ \frac{f'(s)}{q(0)+R_0+\int_{0}^sm*f'(u)du} \right ] ds</math>setting it equal to <math>b</math> and solving for <math>t=t^*</math> gives you the desired stopping time <math>t^*=E_0[L_B]</math>. There is no simple formula for the expected values of fractions, so we make no further elaboration of the general case in this presentation. However, Jensen’s inequality allows us to give an estimate of the general case, and the following calculations give an upper limit. Now assume the rate of fees is constant <math>f'(s)=f'_0</math> and no further BOND tokens are minted during the lifetime <math>L_B</math>. Then there is a minor change in the previous formulas<math display="block">f_B^1(t)=\int_{0}^{t} \frac{f'_0}{q_0+R_0+smf'_0}ds=\frac{1}{m}ln\left ( \frac{q+R_0+mtf'_0}{q+R_0}\right )</math>Therefore, to pay a developer <math>q</math> tokens that will have payout with value <math>$b</math> at time <math>L_B</math> we solve the equation <math display="inline">f_B^1(L_B)=b</math> for <math>L_B</math>''.'' We get <math display="block">L_B=(q+R_0) \frac{e^{mb}-1}{mf'_0}</math> Further, we can find the present value of a single BOND token with arbitrary lifetime <math>L_B</math> under the assumption of constant fees is<math display="block">PVf_B^1=\int_0^{L_B}e^{-rt}\frac{d}{dt}f_B^1(t)dt=\frac{1}{m}exp\left ( \frac{r(q+R_0)}{mf'_0} \right)\int_{\frac{r(q+R_0)}{mf'_0}}^{L_B}\frac{e^{-s}}{s}ds</math> Therefore we have the following solutions: '''Proposition 5:''' ''Assume the rate of fees is constant <math>f'_0</math> and that no further'' BOND ''tokens are minted during the lifetime <math>L_B</math>.'' ''Then <math>q</math> ''BOND ''tokens will have payout <math>$b</math> by time <math>L_B</math> at a payout rate of <math>qf'_0</math> by setting the lifetime of a'' BOND ''to be<math display="block">L_B=(q+R_0) \frac{e^{mb}-1}{mf'_0}</math>'' ''Again, assuming constant rate of fees, if you wish to pay a developer <math>q</math> ''BOND ''tokens with arbitrary predetermined lifetime <math>0 \leq L_B \leq \infty</math> that will have expected present value worth <math>$b</math> solve the following equation for <math>q</math><math display="block">b=q\frac{1}{m}exp\left ( \frac{r(q+R_0)}{mf'_0} \right)\int_{\frac{r(q+R_0)}{mf'_0}}^{L_B}\frac{e^{-s}}{s}ds \qquad \quad {\scriptstyle\text{(Equation 7)}}</math>'' Equation 7 has no elementary solution, but admits efficient solutions through standard numerical approximation algorithms. However, next we assume the REP tokens have finite lifetimes, which guarantees explicit elementary solutions. === Fixed-period BOND contracts under finite-lifetime REP === Next, we consider the situation when there is a finite lifetime ''<math>L<\infty</math>'' on a DAO's REP tokens. We make the further assumptions of constant minting ratio ''<math>m</math>'' and constant fees ''<math>f'_0</math>''. We assume the BOND tokens are minted after the system reaches equilibrium. In this case, there are always ''<math>R_{\infty}=mf'_0L</math>'' of the REP tokens in the system. Then diluting the system with ''<math>q</math>'' artificially minted BOND tokens at time ''<math>t_0=0</math>'' which have the same lifetime ''<math>L_B=L</math>'' gives''<math display="block">f_B^1 (t)=f_0^1 (t)= \begin{cases}t \frac{f'_0}{q+mf'_0L} & \text{if }t\leq L \\ \frac{f'_0L}{q+mf'_0L} & \text{if }t\geq L \end{cases}</math>'' So<math display="block">PVf_B^1=\int_0^\infty e^{-rt} \frac{d}{dt} f_0^1 (t)dt=\frac{f'_0}{q+mf'_0L}\int_0^L e^{-rt}dt=\frac{f'_0}{q+mf'_0L}\left ( \frac{1-e^{-rL}}{r}\right ).</math>Therefore we solve the equation <math>qPVf_B^1=b</math> for <math>q</math> to get '''Proposition 6:''' A''ssume the rate of fees <math>f'_0</math>'' ''is constant, and the lifetime of all tokens (REP and BONDs) is <math>L<\infty</math>. To pay a bounty with present value worth <math>$b</math> a DAO can mint <math>q</math> BOND tokens where<math display="block">q= \frac{brmf'_0L}{f'_0(1-e^{-rL})-rb}</math>'' Similar calculations can be made to get the formula for the number of BOND tokens when we choose the lifetime independently of the lifetime of the normal REP tokens. Notice Proposition 6 gives a bound on the value ''<math>$b</math>'' of BOND tokens that can be minted based on the amount of fees ''<math>f'_0</math>'' the DAO is earning ''<math display="inline">b<f'_0(1-e^{-rL})/r</math>''. The major problem with these formulas is that the assumption that the rate of fees ''<math>f'_0</math>'' is constant is false and will often be very inaccurate, especially when a DAO is small. The above solutions make BONDs a gamble for both the developer and the DAO. If the rate of fees ''<math>f'</math>'' increases during the lifetime ''<math>L_B</math>'' then the reward’s value will be greater than ''<math>$b</math>'', and if the rate of fees decreases it will be worth less. However, as mentioned above, Jensen’s inequality gives us a bound, showing these results are conservative. Specifically, if the fees’ rate is not constant, but that the fees merely have expected value ''<math>f'_0</math>'' then these formulas will be generous to the BOND holder. If however, the actual values of the fees have an average less than this expected value, the BOND holders can still end with less than ''<math>$b</math>'' remuneration in present value. Such uncertainties can be eliminated by more complicated contracts which have [[Riskless BONDs|variable lifetimes]]. == Code == ==Applications== ==See Also== * [[Riskless BONDs]] * ==Notes & References==
Summary:
Please note that all contributions to DAO Governance Wiki may be edited, altered, or removed by other contributors. If you do not want your writing to be edited mercilessly, then do not submit it here.
You are also promising us that you wrote this yourself, or copied it from a public domain or similar free resource (see
DAO Governance Wiki:Copyrights
for details).
Do not submit copyrighted work without permission!
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Navigation menu
Personal tools
Not logged in
Talk
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Namespaces
Page
Discussion
English
Views
Read
Edit
Edit source
View history
More
Search
Navigation
Main page
Recent changes
Random page
Help about MediaWiki
Tools
What links here
Related changes
Special pages
Page information